Settlement
of Land during the British Rule | Indian History
The following points highlight the three main types of settlement
of land during the British rule. The types are: 1. The Permanent Settlement
2. The Ryotwari Settlement 3. The Mahalwari System.
v
Settlement
of Land: Type 1. The Permanent
Settlement:
We have seen
that in 1765, the East India Company acquired the Diwani, or control over the
revenues, of Bengal, Bihar and Orissa. Initially, it made an attempt to
continue the old system of revenue collection though it increased the amount to
be collected from Rs 14,290,000 in 1722 and Rs 18,180,000 in 1764 to Rs
23,400,000 in 1771.
In 1773, it
decided to manage the land revenues directly. Warren Hastings auctioned the
right to collect revenue to the highest bidders. But his experiment did not
succeed. Though the amount of land revenue was pushed high by zamindars and
other speculators bidding against each other, the actual collection varied from
year to year and seldom came up to official expectations.
This introduced
instability in the Company’s revenues at a time when the Company was hard
pressed for money. Moreover, neither the ryot nor the zamindar would do
anything to improve cultivation when they did not know what the next year’s
assessment would be or who would be the next year’s revenue collector.
It was at this
stage that the idea first emerged of fixing the land revenue at a permanent
amount. Finally, after prolonged discussion and debate, the Permanent
Settlement was introduced in Bengal and Bihar in 1793 by Lord Cornwallis. It
had two special features. First, the zamindars and revenue collectors were
converted into so many landlords.
They were not
only to act as agents of the government in collecting land revenue from the
ryot but also to become the owners of the entire land in their zamindaris.
Their right of ownership was made hereditary and transferable. On the other
hand the cultivators were reduced to the low status of mere tenants and were
deprived of long-standing rights to the soil and other customary rights.
The use of the
pasture and forest lands, irrigation canals, fisheries, and homestead plots and
protection against enhancement of rent were some of the rights which were
sacrificed. In fact, the tenantry of Bengal and Bihar was left entirely at the
mercy of the zamindars. This was done so that the zamindars might be able to
pay in time the exorbitant land revenue demand of the Company.
Second, the
zamindars were to give 10/11th of the rental they derived from the peasantry to
the state, keeping only 1/11th for themselves. But the sums to be paid by them
as land revenue were fixed in perpetuity.
If the rental of
a zamindar’s estate increased owing to extension of cultivation and improvement
in agriculture, or his capacity to extract more from his tenants, or any other
reason, he would keep the entire amount of the increase.
The state would
not make any further demand upon him. At the same time, the zamindar had to pay
his revenue rigidly on the due date even if the crop had failed for some
reason; otherwise his lands were to be sold.
The initial
fixation of revenue was made arbitrarily and without any consultation with the
zamindars. The attempt of the officials was to secure the maximum amount. As a
result, the rates of revenue were fixed very high. Between 1765-66 and 1793,
land revenue demand nearly doubled.
John Shore, the
man who planned the Permanent Settlement and later succeeded Cornwallis as
Governor-General, calculated that if the gross produce of Bengal be taken as
100, the government claimed 45, zamindars and other intermediaries below them
received 15, and only 40 remained with the actual cultivator.
One result of
this high and impossible land revenue demand was that nearly half the zamindari
lands were put up for sale between 1794 and 1807.
It was later
generally admitted by officials and non-officials alike that before 1793 the
zamindars of Bengal and Bihar did not enjoy proprietary rights over most of the
land. The question then arises: why did the British recognise them as such?
One explanation
is that this was in part the result of a misunderstanding. In England, the
central figure in agriculture at the time was the landlord and the British
officials made the mistake of thinking that the zamindar was his Indian
counterpart.
It is, however,
to be noted that in one crucial respect the British officials clearly
differentiated between the positions of the two. The landlord in Britain was
the owner of land not only in relation to the tenant but also in relation to
the state.
But in Bengal
while the zamindar was landlord over the tenant, he was himself subordinated to
the state. In fact he was reduced virtually to the status of a tenant of the
East India Company.
In contrast to
the British landlord, who paid a small share of his income as land tax, he had
to pay as tax 10/11th of his income from the land of which he was supposed to
be the owner; and he could be turned out of the land unceremoniously and his
estate sold if he failed to pay the revenue in time.
Other historians
think that the decision to recognise the zamindars as the proprietors of land
was basically determined by political, financial and administrative expediency.
Here the guiding factors were three. The first arose out of clever statecraft:
the need to create political allies.
The British
officials realised that as they were foreigners in India, their rule would be
unstable unless they acquired local supporters who would act as a buffer
between them and the people of India. This argument had immediate importance as
there were a large number of popular revolts in Bengal during the last quarter
of the eighteenth century.
So they brought
into existence a wealthy and privileged class of zamindars which owed its
existence to British rule and which would, therefore, be compelled by its own
basic interests to support it.
This expectation
was, in fact, fully justified later when the zamindars as a class supported the
foreign government in opposition to the rising movement for freedom. Second,
and perhaps the predominant motive, was that of financial security. Before 1793
the Company was troubled by fluctuations in its chief source of income, the
land revenue.
The Company was
faced with a constant financial crisis as Bengal revenue had to finance its
army engaged in wars of expansion, the civil establishment in Bengal, Madras
and Bombay, and the purchase of manufactures for export. The Permanent
Settlement guaranteed stability of income. The newly created property of the
zamindars acted as a security of this.
Moreover, the
Permanent Settlement enabled the Company to maximise its income as land revenue
was now fixed higher than it had ever been in the past. Collection of revenue
through a small number of zamindars seemed to be much simpler and cheaper than
the process of dealing with lakhs of cultivators.
Third, the
Permanent Settlement was expected to increase agricultural production. Since
the land revenue would not be increased in future even if the zamindar’s income
went up, the latter would be inspired to extend cultivation and improve
agricultural productivity as was being done in Britain by its landlords.
The Permanent
Zamindari Settlement was later extended to Orissa, the Northern Districts of
Madras, and the District of Varanasi.
In parts of
Central India and Awadh the British introduced a temporary zamindari settlement
under which the zamindars were made owners of land but the revenue they had to
pay was revised periodically. Another group of landlords was created all over
India when the government started the practice of giving land to persons who
had rendered faithful service to the foreign rulers.
v
Settlement
of Land: Type 2. The Ryotwari Settlement:
The
establishment of British rule in south and south-western India brought new
problems of land settlement. The officials believed that in these regions there
were no zamindars with large estates with whom settlement of land revenue could
be made and that the introduction of zamindari system would upset the existing
state of affairs.
Many Madras
officials led by Reed and Munro recommended that settlement should, therefore,
be made directly with the actual cultivators. They also pointed out that under
the Permanent Settlement the Company was a financial loser as it had to share
the revenues with the zamindars and could not claim a share of the growing
income from land.
Moreover, the
cultivator was left at the mercy of the zamindar who could oppress him at will.
Under the system they proposed, which is known as the Ryotwari Settlement, the
cultivator was to be recognised as the owner of his plot of land subject to the
payment of land revenue.
The supporters
of the Ryotwari system claimed that it was a continuation of the state of
affairs that had existed in the past.
Munro said:
“It is the
system which has always prevailed in India.”
The Ryotwari
Settlement was in the end introduced in parts of the Madras and Bombay
Presidencies in the beginning of the nineteenth century. The settlement under
the Ryotwari system was not made permanent. It was revised periodically after
20 to 30 years when the revenue demand was usually raised.
The Ryotwari
Settlement did not bring into existence a system of peasant ownership. The
peasant soon discovered that the large number of zamindars had been replaced by
one giant zamindar— the state—and that they were mere government tenants whose
land was sold if they failed to punctually pay land revenue. In fact, the
government later openly claimed that land revenue was rent and not a tax.
The ryot’s rights of ownership of his land were also negated by
three other factors:
1. In most areas
the land revenue fixed was exorbitant; the ryot was hardly left with bare
maintenance even in the best of seasons. For instance, in Madras the government
claim was fixed as high as 45 to 55 per cent of gross production in the
settlement. The situation was nearly as bad in Bombay.
2. The
government retained the right to enhance land revenue at will.
3. The ryot had
to pay revenue even when his produce was partially or wholly destroyed by
drought or floods.
v
Settlement
of Land: Type 3. The
Mahalwari System:
A modified
version of the zamindari settlement, introduced in the Ganga valley, the
North-West Provinces, parts of central India, and the Punjab, was known as the
Mahalwari System. The revenue settlement was to be made village by village or
estate (mahal) by estate with landlords or heads of families who collectively
claimed to be the landlords of the village or the estate.
In the Punjab a
modified Mahalwari System known as the village system was introduced. In
Mahalwari areas also, the land revenue was periodically revised. Both the
Zamindari and the Ryotwari systems departed fundamentally from the traditional
land systems of the country.
The British
created a new form of private property in land in such a way that the benefit
of the innovation did not go to the cultivators. All over the country, land was
now made saleable, mortgageable, and alienable. This was done primarily to
protect the government’s revenue.
If land had not
been made transferable or saleable, the government would find it very difficult
to realise revenue from a cultivator who had no savings or possessions out of
which to pay it. Now he could borrow money on the security of this land or even
sell part of it and pay his land revenue.
If he refused to
do so, the government could and often did auction his land and realise the
amount. Another reason for introducing private ownership of land was provided
by the belief that only right of ownership would make the landlord or the ryot
exert himself in making improvements.
The British by
making land a commodity which could be freely bought and sold introduced a
fundamental change in the existing land systems of the country. The stability
and the continuity of the Indian villages were shaken. In fact, the entire
structure of rural society began to break up.
No comments:
Post a Comment